The Great Debt Delusion: How Math Keeps Proving Austerity Wrong (2024)

The Great Debt Delusion: How Math Keeps Proving Austerity Wrong (1)

Ignore the mistakes behind my austerity study, says Harvard professor Ken Rogoff (Reuters)

Well, it turns out history does repeat itself as farce. Especially when it comes to selling austerity.

Back in 2010, policymakers decided the economic crisis was over. Fiscal and monetary stimulus had prevented the Great Recession from turning into a great depression, and that was enough for them to pretty much declare mission accomplished. It was time for policy to go back to "normal", even though the economy had not. In other words, it was time for austerity and higher interest rates, low growth and high unemployment be damned.

There was just one small problem. It was impossible to justify tighter budgets and tighter money when the economy was still depressed. Contractionary policy is, well, contractionary, and the U.S. and Europe certainly didn't need more of that with unemployment still in the double digits.

Unless austerity isn't contractionary. Maybe cutting spending and raising taxes is good for growth!

That was the conclusion of a paper byAlberto Alesina and Silvia Ardagnathat quickly became the Holy Grail of austerians everywhere. Alesina and Ardagna looked at times when advanced countries had cut their deficits in the past 40 years, and found that austerity was often expansionary, particularly when it was weighted towards spending cuts rather than tax hikes. But this wasn't quite the intellectual coup it looked like. For one, Alesina and Ardagna didn't do a very good job identifying when countries did or didn't do austerity-- their sample missed some pretty big counter-examples. For another, asMike Konczal and Arjun Jayadevof the Roosevelt Institute showed, almost none of the countries started austerity amidst a slump, and all of them could (and did) cut interest rates to offset their deficit-cutting. In other words, Alesina and Ardagna wasn't relevant to our zero-interest rate, low-growth world.

Okay, so austerity isn't expansionary in the short-run, but maybe it's expansionary in the long-run. That was the conclusion of a paper by Carmen Reinhart and Ken Rogoff that quickly became the new Holy Grail of austerians everywhere. Reinhart and Rogoff looked at times when advanced countries have had debt of at least 90 percent of GDP going back to 1946, and found that growth tends to be much lower during these periods. Reinhart and Rogoff argued this shows that higher debt causes lower growth -- which would mean austerity causes higher growth, at least in the long run.

There are lots of problems here. Most obviously, this correlation between high debt and low growth doesn't prove much. Deficits and debt go up during a slump as tax revenue falls and safety-net spending rises. That doesn't mean debt and deficits cause the slump; the opposite. That alone is reason to discount this fiscal doomsaying. But now there might be another.

It turns out Reinhart and Rogoff might have gotten some of their data wrong. As Mike Konczal reports -- and you really need to read the link -- a new paper by Thomas Herndon, Michael Ash, and Robert Pollin of the University of Massachusetts, Amherst, identifies two big issues. First, and most amusingly, Reinhart and Rogoff seem to have made an Excel formula error. (Yes, really). As you can see below, they apparently only averaged the first 14 countries in their sample, and forgot to drag down for the last five. Oops.

The Great Debt Delusion: How Math Keeps Proving Austerity Wrong (2)

This Excel error "only" reduced their growth average by 0.3 percentage points, which although not good, isn't as bad as their other mistake. That was using the wrong number for New Zealand. Now, Reinhart and Rogoff have a straightforward enough methodology. They calculate each country's average growth for each year it had debt over 90 percent of GDP, and then average those country averages. But they didn't calculate the average for New Zealand. They just used one year instead. This skewed the result more than you might think, since the averageshould have been 2.6 percent, and Reinhart and Rogoff used one year that had -7.6 percent growth. Double oops.

But is Reinhart and Rogoff's methodology even the right one? That's not clear. Because they just average the country averages, Reinhart and Rogoff weigh each equally, regardless of whether they had one year of bad growth or many years of decent growth. That's not necessarily wrong, but if you average all the years, rather than all the countries, you get 2.2 percent growth, versus the -0.1 percent Reinhart and Rogoff reported.

This brouhaha has been equal parts distracting and revealing. The Herndon, Ash, and Pollin paper doesn't change the big picture all that much. Growth does tend to slow down when debt is high, just not as much as Reinhart and Rogoff claimed. But whether it slows down to 2.2 percent or -0.1 percent doesn't really matter. What matters is whether it's the higher debt causing the slower growth, whatever that may be. There's still no evidence of that, and never has been.

But that doesn't mean this dispute has just been a sideshow. It should be astonishing that such an apparently shoddy paper has been as influential as it has. Now, policymakers didn't pursue austerity because of Reinhart and Rogoff, but it was the best argument they had for doing so. And they used it a lot. Think about that. A paper that couldn't even manage to enter numbers into a spreadsheet correctly became the chief intellectual justification for a horribly self-defeating economic experiment that has kept millions out of work.

We're finding out with how little wisdom the world is governed, one Excel error at a time.

Matthew O'Brien is a former senior associate editor at The Atlantic.

The Great Debt Delusion: How Math Keeps Proving Austerity Wrong (2024)

FAQs

What is the controversy between Reinhart and Rogoff? ›

Economics professor L. Randall Wray criticized Reinhart and Rogoff for combining data "across centuries, exchange rate regimes, public and private debt, and debt denominated in foreign currency as well as domestic currency," in addition to "statistical errors," and for lacking a "theory of sovereign currency".

Did Keynes support austerity? ›

John Maynard Keynes became a well known anti-austerity economist, arguing that "The boom, not the slump, is the right time for austerity at the Treasury." Contemporary Keynesian economists argue that budget deficits are appropriate when an economy is in recession, to reduce unemployment and help spur GDP growth.

What is the argument for austerity? ›

Economists disagree on whether austerity measures work as they are intended to. Supporters of austerity measures argue that large deficits are damaging to the broader economy, which can limit tax revenue. Austerity, under this argument, is effective because it lowers government spending and decreases deficits.

Is austerity the same as deficit spending? ›

Austerity measures are considered harsh economic policies intended to reduce the government's budget deficit. These policies can include reductions in government spending and increased taxes. Austerity measures are commonly used with contractionary fiscal policy or when a government faces debt default.

What was the error in Reinhart Rogoff Excel? ›

They actually found, using a different method, that the economic growth would be around 2.2 percent. Reinhart and Rogoff admitted that their spreadsheet was accidentally omitting 5 rows in an Average formula, and claimed that the corrected result would be a positive growth but of just 0.2 percent.

Does high public debt consistently stifle economic growth? ›

Government debt has positive effects on economic growth, but when it increases over a certain threshold, it will become a burden and have negative effects on the economy.

Did Hayek believe in austerity? ›

Yet only one school of economic thought, that of Friedrich Hayek and Ludwig von Mises, predicted and prescribed austerity before the Great Recession.

Was Keynes a socialist or capitalist? ›

No, Keynes was not a capitalist. He was, though, pro-capitalism. Like many another socialist of his day, he'd come to the realization that socialism would never succeed without a strong core of free enterprise to generate wealth.

Who invented austerity? ›

To counter these trends, Mattei argues, unelected technocratic elites 'invented' austerity as a means of re-naturalizing the capital order. . . . What Britain's technocrats accomplished through the market, Italy's fascists accomplished through Mussolini's edicts. . .

Is austerity a virtue? ›

Austerity and minimalism are virtues. They fit nicely alongside other virtues like simplicity, self-discipline and clarity. They help us beat back vices like excess hedonism or destructive snacking.

What is the opposite of austerity in economics? ›

While austerity increases inequality by curbing public services and benefitting the rich through tax cuts and privatisation of government services, degrowth policies focus on democratising production, curbing the wealth and overconsumption of the rich, expanding public services, and increasing equality within and ...

What are the cons of austerity? ›

The economy suffers. Particularly if you implement austerity measures during periods of weak economic growth because it can cause a recession or make it worse if one is underway. Everyone spends less, there is higher unemployment and an increased brain drain. The social impact can be high.

Does austerity cause deflation? ›

Austerity is a form of voluntary deflation in which the economy adjusts through the reduction of wages, prices, and public spending to restore competitiveness, which is (supposedly) best achieved by cutting the state's budget, debts, and deficits.

How is globalization the end of austerity? ›

The age of austerity, which was a response to fiscal crises and economic challenges, is being reshaped by the forces of globalization. The interconnectedness of economies, cross-border financial integration, and global supply chains have introduced new complexities to the austerity debate.

What is the meaning of brutal austerity? ›

Austerity is a situation in which people's living standards are reduced because of economic difficulties.

What type of economy did Keynes support? ›

Therefore, Keynesian economics supports a mixed economy guided mainly by the private sector but partly operated by the government. Prices, and especially wages, respond slowly to changes in supply and demand, resulting in periodic shortages and surpluses, especially of labor.

Did Keynes believe in deficit spending? ›

Stabilizing the economy

For example, Keynesian economists would advocate deficit spending on labor-intensive infrastructure projects to stimulate employment and stabilize wages during economic downturns. They would raise taxes to cool the economy and prevent inflation when there is abundant demand-side growth.

What idea did Keynes reject? ›

Keynes rejected the idea that the economy would return to a natural state of equilibrium.

Did Keynes believe in monetarism? ›

Monetarists believe in fighting inflation by adjusting the amount of money in circulation. Keynesians acknowledge some value in monetarism's effect on GDP but feel that monetary adjustments take too long to be felt.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Lakeisha Bayer VM

Last Updated:

Views: 6529

Rating: 4.9 / 5 (69 voted)

Reviews: 92% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Lakeisha Bayer VM

Birthday: 1997-10-17

Address: Suite 835 34136 Adrian Mountains, Floydton, UT 81036

Phone: +3571527672278

Job: Manufacturing Agent

Hobby: Skimboarding, Photography, Roller skating, Knife making, Paintball, Embroidery, Gunsmithing

Introduction: My name is Lakeisha Bayer VM, I am a brainy, kind, enchanting, healthy, lovely, clean, witty person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.